Begin typing your search...
Pandemic and the prisoner’s dilemma
Using game theory, researchers modelled two ways of prioritising vaccinations, to see which saved more lives
Chennai
Madhur Anand, an ecologist, and her husband, Chris Bauch, a mathematical biologist (inset), were optimally situated during the spring lockdown, working from home in Guelph, Ontario, to watch the pandemic play out — and to discuss patterns of behaviour, within their community and beyond, as we all tried to keep safe and carry on. Their offices at home are separated only by a wall, rather than a 45-minute drive. Dr Anand is the director of the new Guelph Institute for Environmental Research at the University of Guelph, and Dr Bauch runs a lab at the University of Waterloo.
The couple’s collaborative research usually focuses on the interplay between human behaviour and environment systems — for instance, with pollution, deforestation and climate change. Whereas those dynamics unfold slowly, the pandemic provided an acute example of rapid change. “Societal change is not the kind of thing you can easily experiment with,” Dr Anand said.
“But here we were in the middle of a huge social experiment.” Like many scientists, they redirected their research to COVID-19. The resulting study, led by their doctoral student Peter Jentsch and currently under peer review, looked at vaccination prioritisation: To save the most lives, who should get the vaccine first? As infectious disease studies go, their methodology was somewhat atypical because it applied game theory, a mathematical way of modelling how people make strategic decisions within a group.
Each individual has choices, but the payoff for each choice depends on choices made by others. This is what’s called a “prisoner’s dilemma game” — players weigh cooperation against betrayal, often producing a less than optimal outcome for the common good. The pandemic presents an everyday complexity of such choices. Imagine, Dr Bauch said, if everyone followed public health recommendations: They wore masks, socially distanced, washed their hands, followed stay-at-home orders. “In that case there is a significantly reduced risk of infection,” he said.
But there are always trade-offs and temptations to defect from the regimen. Masks are annoying. Hand-washing is tedious. You need a hug. “The pandemic is a prisoner’s dilemma game played out repeatedly,” Dr Bauch said. In lectures, he invokes a comparison between Ayn Rand, who made a virtue of selfishness, and the “Star Trek” character Spock, who said, “The needs of the many outweigh the needs of the few.” Now the vaccine adds one more protective layer. The perceived benefits and costs of vaccination are often expressed as concerns about safety and side effects. If you are on the fence about vaccination, you might decide — noticing lower infection rates as vaccination campaigns gain speed — that it no longer seems so critical to get the jab.
“Some people might play a ‘wait-and-see game,’” Dr Bauch said. People who choose not to be vaccinated effectively get a free ride, reaping the benefits of reduced virus transmission generated by the people who do opt for vaccination. But the free rides generate a collective threat.
“That is the prisoner’s dilemma,” Dr Bauch said. When infection levels are low, people feel less at risk, let down their guard, and then infection levels again rise; the ebb and flow between our behaviour and the virus causes the pandemic waves. “We end up in this unhappy medium,” he said.
The origins of game theory can be found in the 1944 book “Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour,” by the mathematician John von Neumann and the economist Oskar Morgenstern. The applications range from evolution to psychology to computer science; there’s even a book called “The Game Theorist’s Guide to Parenting.” Dr Bauch did pioneering work combining game theory and epidemiological modelling, with colleagues including Alison Galvani, an epidemiologist and the director of the Yale Center for Infectious Disease Modelling and Analysis. “Vaccination decisions based purely on self-interest can lead to vaccination coverage that is lower than what is optimal for society overall,” Dr Galvani said in an email.
The self-interest strategy maximizing individual payoff is called the Nash equilibrium. Dr Galvani’s later research included psychological data and demonstrated that vaccination decisions can be influenced by altruism, thereby boosting uptake beyond the Nash equilibrium and serving the common good.
She noted, however, that game theory assumes people are rational in their decision-making. Fear can suppress vaccination “to precarious levels insufficient to prevent the spread of an outbreak,” she said.
A 2019 investigation using game theory to study vaccination showed that vaccine hesitancy could be explained by a mathy mechanism called “hysteresis.” In general terms, hysteresis occurs when the effects of a force persist even after the force is removed — the response lags. Paper clips exposed to a magnetic field still cling together after the field is turned off; unemployment rates can remain high even in a recovery economy.
Similarly, even after a vaccine is deemed safe and efficacious, uptake rates often remain low. “The hysteresis effect makes the population hysterical, or sensitive, to the perceived risks of the vaccine,” said Xingru Chen, a doctoral student in mathematics at Dartmouth College, and the paper’s co-author, with her adviser Feng Fu, a mathematician and biomedical data scientist (who recently applied a similar approach to the dilemma of social distancing).
“It boils down to a fundamental problem known as the tragedy of the commons,” Chen said. “There is a misalignment of individual interests and societal interests.” To overcome the hysteresis effect, she said, vaccination should be promoted as an act of altruism — one’s personal contribution to defeating the pandemic.
A subsequent iteration of the coronavirus game-theory study explored how vaccine compliance affects the number of deaths prevented.
If a small subset of the population chooses not to get the vaccine, it affects us all, said Dr Anand, who is also an author and a poet.
Incorporating game theory, Jentsch said, injects an interesting dose of “realism.” It captures how people respond to the ups and downs of daily existence, and how our actions in turn make all the difference. An army of umbrellas won’t change the weather, but vaccination can be a powerful force in defeating the coronavirus.
Vaccination campaigns now underway in Canada and the United States follow the direct protection approach. Because the coronavirus is more widespread south of the shared border, “the best time for the ‘switch’ to indirect protection may occur sooner in the U.S.,” Dr Bauch said. Also, he noted, “indirect protection could be a useful route for low- and middle-income countries who will not get the vaccine as soon as wealthy countries.”
Siobhan Roberts is a reporter with NYT©2020
The New York Times
Visit news.dtnext.in to explore our interactive epaper!
Download the DT Next app for more exciting features!
Click here for iOS
Click here for Android
Next Story